May 14, 1999 -- TOGETHER with his deputy, Lawrence Summers, and Alan
Greenspan, the US Federal Reserve chairman, Robert Rubin, the US treasury
secretary, has over the past four years formed a team akin to the legendary
Three Musketeers, playing a decisive role in laying the groundwork to maintain
the momentum of the longest US economic expansion in the post-war period.
His equally important achievement was his ability to tame the global
financial crisis, preventing it from hitting US shores and dragging the world's
economy down with it.
His departure, effective on July 4, will bring to an end a spectacular era,
in which the spirit of free markets has unquestionably reigned supreme in the
conduct of the Clinton Administration's economic and financial policies.
From his command centre on the third floor of the US Treasury, where he and
Summers share a suit facing the Washington Monument, Rubin has won praise for
his skills at marrying international finance and foreign policy. A wonder boy
who ran Goldman Sachs' arbitrage operations, he left the Wall Street firm after
26 years of dedicated service to join the Clinton Administration as chairman of
the National Economic Council before becoming the treasury secretary.
At the treasury, Rubin runs the organisation ''more like an investment
bank,'' quipped Tim Geithner, the undersecretary for international affairs.
He enjoys debating with his staff and eliciting opinions from them rather
than taking their straight recommendations. His legacy is the present strong US
economic expansion, which has brought unprecedented prosperity to Americans.
This can be traced back to the 1993 deficit-reduction plan, which was one of
Clinton's campaign promises that Rubin helped navigate through Congress. The
fiscal discipline created the first budget surplus in 29 years, helping
Greenspan to bring down interest rates and give the economy a good kick-start.
Then Rubin, Greenspan and Summers let the free markets work their way. The
reinventing of US businesses, which were in trouble throughout the second half
of the previous decade, has strengthened their competitiveness.
Innovations and the advance of technology have brought down the cost of doing
business. High-tech companies have paraded into the stock market to fuel the
spectacular rise of share prices. US financial institutions are also the
strongest and most competitive in the world. The Americans look invincible, with
rising living standards. Everything they do is right. On the contrary, what the
Japanese, and the rest of Asia, have been doing or preaching are wrong.
The success of Rubin, Greenspan and Summers ''has turned them into a kind of
free-market Politburo on economic matters.'' The three, Greenspan in particular,
have faith in the free market and have an appetite for analysis of the markets,
which they believe will be correct in the end. To Greenspan, ''markets are an
expression of the deepest truths about human nature and that, as a result, they
will ultimately be correct.'' Time, Feb 15, 1999, Page 37).
In real life, however, the markets can be imperfect due to the involvement of
human emotions and a host of other factors. Rubin would set out to tame the
market like a man riding a tiger's back.
The Thai crisis was no surprise to Rubin and his team. For two years before
the Bank of Thailand floated the baht in 1997, Greenspan and Rubin had been
watching the narrowing of the spread between US government bonds and the
emerging-market bonds with disquiet.
Banks were lending money to countries like Thailand or Malaysia at rates
close to the US treasuries. In other words, Thailand and Malaysia were not
riskier than the US. That was impossible. Rubin and Greenspan believed that a
correction would be inevitable, though they could not imagine that it would
become an Asian contagion.
The Asian crisis took its roots from the lending spree unleashed in the
emerging-market region after the collapse of the New York stock market on Black
Monday, October 19, 1987. The capital flow created unprecedented economic growth
in Asia, reinforcing the myth of the Asian miracle.
Thailand got into problems in the early 1990s when it began to liberalise
financial markets amid poor corporate governance and lax supervision of the
financial system. The easy money loaned to Thai companies and banks went into
land and stock-market speculation and more importantly fuelled the industries
with over-investment.
To make matters worse, the inflexible exchange-rate policy could not cope
with the over-valuation of the baht, pegged to the rising dollar since mid-1995.
A correction would come to pass. In the case of Thailand, it was handled badly.
Foreign-exchange reserves were depleted in the baht defence between late 1996
and the first half of 1997. When the Bank of Thailand floated the baht on July
2, it triggered a regional contagion, which at one point threatened to bring
down other parts of the world.
From the outset, Rubin took an emotionless interest in the Thai crisis. If
Thailand needed help from a bail-out of the International Monetary Fund, in
which the US has a big say, it would have to fully disclose its foreign-exchange
swap contracts to the global financial markets.
At that point, the Thai central bank was locking horns with US hedge funds,
which had taken massive bets against the Thai baht through the foreign-exchange
swap contracts. In total, the Thai officials built up US$30 billion in swap
contracts to defend the integrity of the baht peg. Making public this sensitive
information was tantamount to revealing to your enemies movements of your troops
and strategic supplies.
Losing all the reserves from the gruelling defence, Thai officials finally
gave in because the message from Washington was clear that without revealing the
swap contracts the IMF would not step in to help Thailand out. After the swap
contracts were disclosed a few days before Thailand entered the IMF programme in
August 1997, the financial markets panicked with a big cry that Thailand was
insolvent.
From Washington, Rubin and Summers played a key role in overseeing the
formation of the bail-out package for Thailand. They underestimated the crisis,
believing that confidence would be quickly brought back once Thailand was
willing to embrace a strong dose of fiscal and monetary tightening, followed
with structural reforms in the financial and economic sectors.
By the way, Rubin already had experience from dealing with the Mexico peso
crisis. The Thai package, as it turned out, was modelled after the Mexican
bail-out. Mexico, which suffered the crisis in 1993, recovered quickly because
it had a big brother in the north to absorb its exports. Unfortunately for
Thailand, Japan was too weak to pull Thailand out of the crisis because it was
still in the middle of a economic recession, which had started in 1990. Other
regional economies, which depended on Japan, were also in trouble. The collapse
of Asia would be spectacular, from Thailand, to Korea and Indonesia.
Much of the criticism of the early rescue package for Thailand centred on the
requirements of fiscal tightening at a time when the economy was contracting
fast. Yet a classic IMF programme is to squeeze the economy to the core and get
rid of all the fat before the body of the economy can recover again from a
return of confidence or capital inflow.
Of course, Rubin would not accept this mistake of prescribing too harshly
these conditions on Thailand in the initial period. The general sentiment among
the US policy-makers was that Thailand's and other Asian nation's elite should
be punished for their crony capitalism and nepotism. The harsh terms in the
programme would wipe out all the Thai banks and big corporations saddled with
foreign debts that they could not repay. If Thailand was to emerge again, it
would be through better governance, democracy and support from the middle-class.
Then the free-market would work again.
However, the Rubin-designed package for Thailand was completed without the US
government having to contribute a single dollar. Most of the money came from the
IMF, the World Bank, Japan and other neighbouring countries. The US stood at the
sidelines, looking at Thailand as an isolated problem.
In the meantime, the Asian crisis proved to be a great benefit to the US
since it helped to cool inflation from cheaper exports, while the American
economy was riding on the strong-dollar policy in an upsurge cycle. Otherwise,
Greenspan would have had to tighten his grip on the monetary policy.
It was no secret that relations between Bangkok and Washington were rocky
during the Chavalit government. At one point, the IMF threatened to withdraw
support for Thailand, a factor that led to the downfall of Chavalit Yongchaiyudh
as prime minister.
When the Democrats came to power in November 1997, relations were quickly
restored with the US. Tarrin Nimmanahaeminda, the finance minister, set winning
confidence from the G-7 countries as a priority, most particularly the US, which
were the big creditors of Thailand and the region. Tarrin made his way to
Washington and held talks with Rubin and other top officials. He also received
the honour of meeting President Bill Clinton, who was concerned about Thailand's
misgivings over the US.
Only when the crisis in South Korea broke out in December that same year,
when Korean banks and corporations were on the verge of defaulting on their
massive foreign loans, did Rubin start to act. For Korea represented closer
strategic interests to the US.
Almost single-handedly, Rubin arranged a meeting between the international
bankers and the Koreans to work out a debt rescheduling. That helped to avert
the global crisis, but it would not prevent Korea from seeking a larger bail-out
package from the IMF.
Tarrin got along well with Rubin, for they spoke the same language and shared
a similar financial background. After Summers made his way to Bangkok and said
some soothing words in late January 1998, when overreaction brought the baht
down to a record low of Bt56 to the US dollar, sentiment began to improve.
Yet recovery was still not in sight because of the fragility of the financial
system and the debt overhang. When Rubin travelled to Thailand in mid-1998,
making a spin-off trip from China, he did not pretend that Thailand would
graduate from the crisis conveniently without further hard work at reform. At a
time when the IMF was fiercely criticised for prescribing very harsh conditions
on Thailand, Rubin stood firm behind the IMF, saying that the overall rescue
package for Thailand was adequate.
He said the problems of Thailand and other crisis-hit economies were
difficult and complex and had no easy answers or guarantees.
Asked by Fortune (Sept 28, 1998, page 60) how long the crisis would last,
Rubin said: ''I don't know. But I don't think it's going to be resolved easily
or quickly. There were substantial excesses in lending and credits, and it will
take time to work its way out.''
Despite the crisis, which spread from Thailand to other parts of Asia, Russia
and Latin America, Rubin and his team remained confident that the US would
survive the financial storm unscathed. This was contrary to what George Soros,
the international financier and hedge-fund operator, had predicted with his
doomsday forecast of the downfall of the global capitalist system. The US
economy has demonstrated its resilience against external turmoil as it is
domestic oriented, with about 13 per cent of the GDP accounting for exports.
Weakness in the global markets also flushed the money back from the periphery to
the US financial centre, hence the spectacular rise of US stocks.
Along the way throughout 1998, Rubin, Greenspan and Summers walked the
tight-rope to save the US economy, the last fortress of global growth.
Events in Russia and the collapse of the hedge fund, Long-term Capital
Management, allowed Greenspan to cut interest rates in a series of dramatic
attempts to prevent a credit crunch, which would have hit US stocks and
subsequently US business activity.
Ever since that Greenspan has been cautiously trying to talk the market down
to prevent the US stock market bubble from getting out of hand. The market so
far has not listened to him. And Rubin set forth to preside over the formation
of a new global financial architecture, revolving around the US capitalist model
of trade liberalisation and free flow of capital, in view of the crisis.
Now that he is dismounting from the back of the tiger and leaving Summers to
do the job, Rubin is not expected to sleep well every night until the global
crisis has been effectively brought under control and until the US economy can
work out a soft landing in case of a stock market crash. Summers will inherit
this demanding task and will have to make sure that he is not eaten by the
tiger.
BY THANONG KHANTHONG